Lawrence Lessig, a seemingly reliable advocate for open information, has written a bizarre piece entitled “Against Transparency: The perils of openness in government.” He claims that the US open government movement has grown too powerful and may have gone too far. It goes downhill from there.
First, the piece is here: Against Transparency
Second: A rebuttal from our friends at the Sunlight Foundation, where Lessig is (for now) on an advisory board. (Note to self: talk to advisory board about not penning off-message opinion pieces. — Ed)
Our take…
Lessig has some valid points, which we’ll discuss below. Unfortunately, they are buried in a 6,500 word discourse that tacks from government data in one paragraph to copyright protections the next. Lessig acknowledges “ the good that transparency creates in a wide range of contexts, government especially.” But he also says, “I have increasingly come to worry that there is an error at the core of this unquestioned goodness. We are not thinking critically enough about where and when transparency works, and where and when it may lead to confusion, or to worse.”
OK, maybe. Let’s go down the list of his examples.
Lessig writes: “a campaign to get members of Congress to post their daily calendars on the Internet… there were too many legitimate reasons why someone might not want his or her ‘daily official work schedule’ available to anyone with an Internet connection.”
Security concerns: we get it. Global Integrity has talked with the government of Guatemala about this very issue, and in that context (where people end up dead on the streets because of their political views), there are very real concerns over assassination and kidnap via schedule data. The US Congress? Not so much. Members of Congress do a lot of scheduled events already, apparently without incident. Their campaigns are full of them.
But the point of posting a Member’s schedule is not to know their location; it’s to know what they spend their time on and with who they spend it. These are things that can be posted with no security risk at all: a list of meetings, their length, who was there, what was discussed. Alphabetize it and post it after a week’s delay — security problem solved.
Lessig writes, “Like the decision to go to war in Iraq, transparency has become an unquestionable bipartisan value.”
Wow. The decision to go to war in Iraq remains obviously controversial, and drew hundreds of thousands of people to anti-war protests before the war even began. The open government movement, laboring in obscurity over data formats and FOIA processes, has very little in common with this. Actually, we’re not sure if it has anything to do with it.
In Washington, transparency is far from “unquestionable.” While the Obama administration has proven mildly enthusiastic over the release of government databases, it is conspicuously less so on old fashioned access to information regarding the administration itself.
“A lot of us have been disappointed and confused,” said Anne L. Weisman, chief counsel for Citizens for Responsibility and Ethics in an interview with Global Integrity this summer. “Some of the attitudes are mimicking the anti-transparency attitudes of the Bush Administration.” Particularly at the Justice Department, she says, “This is a culture that has not changed in many ways.” (We examine transparency under Obama at length in the upcoming Global Integrity Report: 2009.)
Lessig is concerned that campaign finance datasets are more suggestive than definitive as proof of corruption: “Where a member of Congress acts in a way inconsistent with his principles or his constituents, but consistent with a significant contribution, that act at least raises a question about the integrity of the decision. But beyond a question, the data says little else.”
Have you read All the President’s Men? Knowing what questions to ask is huge. It’s almost everything. You ask the right questions, you start getting answers, and you piece it together a little at a time. That’s how investigative journalism works.
Lessig: “But will not this supposed salience of money… simply inspire more debate about whether in fact money buys results in Congress?… This is the problem of attention-span.”
Lessig suggests that lots of data will spread the pernicious but unsupported claim that politicians are bought and sold by campaign donors (to think!). But a number of studies have used campaign finance data to demonstrate exactly the opposite, or to show that raising lots of money doesn’t have that much effect on winning elections. We can debate these studies, but the point is that we’re starting with hard evidence and having a rational discussion grounded in facts. That’s much better than any information-poor alternative.
Lessig quotes: “Surveillance cameras followed the attractive young blond woman through the lobby of the midtown Manhattan hotel, kept a glassy eye on her as she rode the elevator up to the 23rd floor and peered discreetly down the hall as she knocked at the door to my room… As a matter of fact, she is my daughter.”
Scary story: pretty blond, creepy camera, vindicated parent. But this is victim fantasy nonsense. Any media outlet that ran with an affair story this easily disproved would be turned into a smoking hole in the ground by a libel suit. There are rules and enforcement mechanisms already in place that mediate public information. And what does this oddly breathy vignette have to do with government transparency?
Back on topic, Lessig looks at what conflict-of-interest disclosure did to the field of medical publishing.“Like most journals in medicine, JAMA required disclosure, and was among the most aggressive in the extent and the reach of the disclosures required. But as attention to disclosure grew in the medical field, the failure to disclose adequately has become a serious charge. Omission is now a serious commission.”
Lessig argues that partially informed accusations over whether doctors fully disclosed their industry connections are somehow worse than entirely uninformed accusations over whether doctors have hidden industry connections. But I’ll concede the point! Let’s just fix it.
If there’s contention over disclosures and unfair tainting of doctors that fail to completely disclose, let’s take it out of their hands. Switch the disclosure system to a big common database where the medical industry reports contracting relationships with doctors, much as foreign lobbyists already do. Doctors can go on publishing at will, disclosing nothing, because their business relationships (already highly regulated) are now public. No half-disclosure, no unfair accusations. [While factchecking this piece, we learned this is sometimes already happening].
Is it ever that easy? Probably not. But the point is that these issues are entirely soluble. We work on this stuff every day.
The wrapup…
At this point in “Against Transparency” Lessig returns to ground he knows well: copyright law and file sharing. His vocal advocacy on these topics made him a hero to tech geeks and legal wonks alike, and he’s much more persuasive here.
From there we get a stirring defense of full public financing of political campaign, but are then whipsawed back to Lessig’s worries over the use of the word “fair” in the titles of legislation causing them to be overturned. Or something. When did Laurence Lessig, co-inventor of the Creative Commons license used on this site and widely respected political activist, turn into a concern troll?
Here’s where we agree with Lessig: Analysis of data is every bit as essential as access to data. And bad political metrics can take on a life of their own (we wrote an entire book about this phenomenon). But bad analysis doesn’t stop when information is scarce; it just gets dumber and louder. Clamping down the information isn’t a solution, because it doesn’t address the real danger in an opaque government: it’s not that information is gone. It’s that information becomes the privileged possession of a powerful few to use or misuse as they please.
We also agree with Lessig that transparency in public life must be balanced against privacy in private life, even for elected officials.
But our researchers in more than one hundred countries worldwide have told us again and again that the barrier to the success of “open information” regimes isn’t the technical concerns. It is the lack of political will to implement them at all. Which makes “Against Transparency” all the more weird, and all the more irrelevant to the real work ahead of us.
— Jonathan Eyler-Werve
— Image by Robert Scoble (cc by)
David, thanks for this response. Since writing this, I've seen a lot of places where transparency "doesn't work" that are in fact information poor, rather than information rich. For example, publishing a student's teacher evaluations can be brutal on effective and demanding but unpopular teachers. But sorting those data by evaluator GPA (easy) or adding assessments of post-graduate success (hard) suddenly provides an entirely different analysis of popularity. Add data, and suddenly transparency works again.
(note, duplicate comments were removed, thanks for posting)
A terrific, well-reasoned rebuttal.
Lessig is a palladin for many good causes… but like Security Expert Bruce Schneier, he can get quite goofy, as well. In this case, his litany of complaints against Transparency consist largely of strawmen, generall expressed thusly:
"If people act very stupidly… and obstinately refuse to notice bad consequences of stupidity… an increase in information may also increase some of the harm arising from that stupidity."
Yeah… well… I guess so.
But, um, the entire Enlightenment experiment is based upon the premise that increased information flows help to actually reduce the level of stupid behavior. NOT because the obstinate misbehavers learn better! But because those who might hold them accountable are empowered to do so, by knowledge,
This is the core essence of all four of the enlightenment's "accountability arenas"… Markets, science, democracy and courts. In each of these competitive and reciprocal accountability is the key creative force and the essential error-correcting mechanism.
The proof is found in simple logic — that all four arenas have always functioned in direct proportion to the extent that the competing and cooperating participants know more. (It is in this area, that economist F. Hayek is strongest.)
Half of Lessig's examples are egregiously flawed in that, by habit, he refuses to consider how the problem that he raises might be solved by MORE LIGHT. By – for example – allowing him and his daughter to catch any voyeurs who are tracking her movements, and denouncing the peeping toms to their mothers.
This obstinate refusal to consider More Light as a potential solution is common among net pundits like Lessig, alas. Although they worry about many of the right things, their dyspeptic grouchitudinousness makes them insist upon strawman fears, instead of solutions that go with the flow of technological change.
With cordial regards,
David Brin
Author of The Transparent Society: Will Technology Make Us Choose Between Privacy and Freedom?
http://www.davidbrin.com